European Commission logo
EU-EMS

EU Economic Modelling System

Economyemploymentresiliencepreparednesseducationsupply chainsinequalitymigration

overview

Economyemploymentresiliencepreparednesseducationsupply chainsinequalitymigration

main purpose

Global integrated modelling system for assessing resilience, preparedness, inequality, migration, education and employment effects as well as long-term structural productivity effects of supply chains, innovation, human capital and SDG policies in EU and European Neighbourhood countries.

summary

EU-EMS is a dynamic spatial general equilibrium model. Originally developed within the EU Horizon 2020 Research and Innovation Programme by the PBL Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency, the JRC contributes to the model development both conceptually and empirically to ensure credibility, salience and legitimacy when providing evidence-based scientific advice and support to EU policy. EU-EMS is used by the European Commission, European Investment Bank, European Parliament, European Union Agency for Fundamental Rights, European Institute of Innovation and Technology as well as EU Member States and European Neighbourhood Policy countries.

EU-EMS is useful both for ex-post policy evaluation and for ex-ante policy impact assessment and provides sector-, region- and time-specific results to provide model-based scientific advice and support to EU policy on resilience, preparedness, supply chain, inequality, migration, education and employment effects as well as structural reforms. All direct, indirect spatial and inter-temporal spillover effects of public investments or EU policies are captured and reported. EU-EMS is suited for assessing distributional impact by immigration status, firm heterogeneity in terms of technology and productivity (efficiency, capital deepening, human resources, green technology).

In order to ensure scientific credibility, a particular attention is being paid to a valid representation of the modelled policy area, the model is embedded in a conceptual framework and agreed by the scientific community as well as backed by the scientific literature, and the results are quantifiable, evidence based. Salience is achieved by adjusting the model to be relevant to information needs of decision makers, contributing to raising awareness and motivation to take policy action, results are understandable and the model output is readily understood by policy makers, results are temporally explicit – considers change over time, as well as scalable and transferable – applicable at different geographical and sectorial scales. To assure legitimacy, prior being used for the policy advise all key assumptions are selected through an inclusive process, a wide acceptance and agreement by the involved stakeholders, the model is fair in its treatment of stakeholders’ opposing views and divergent values, unbiased in its representation of preferences and interests, as well as transparent and clear assumptions are provided.

model type

ownership

Co-ownership (EU & third parties)
Copyright shared between the Netherlands Environmental Assessment Agency PBL and the European Commission.

licence

Licence type
Free Software licence

details on model structure and approach

The dynamic spatial general equilibrium model features discrete time, multi-sector, dynamic discrete choice migration decisions, and investment determined as the solution to an intertemporal consumption-investment problem. The economy consists of many locations that differ in productivity, amenities, bilateral trade costs and bilateral migration costs. There are two types of infinitely-lived agents: workers and factor-owners. Workers are endowed with one unit of labour that is supplied inelasticity and are spatially mobile subject to migration costs. Workers do not have access to an investment technology and hence live “hand to mouth”. They make forward-looking migration decisions, taking into account migration costs and the expected continuation value from optimal future location decisions. Factor-owners are spatially immobile and own the capital stock in their location. They make a forward-looking decision over consumption and investment in this local stock of capital to maximise intertemporal utility. Capital is spatially immobile once installed and depreciates gradually at a constant rate. There are two sources of dynamics in the model: forward-looking investment decisions of the immobile factor (capital structures) and forward-looking migration decisions of the mobile factor (labour). To relax the assumption of perfect foresight, the model is linearised, allowing to derive a closed-form solution for the economy’s transition path in terms of impact conditions, which captures the impact of (policy) shocks in the period in which they occur, and transition conditions, which governs the evolution of the state variables from one period to the next in response to these shocks. The policy impact and transition paths depend on observable trade and migration shares. Agglomeration is captured through clustering forces in production (productivity spillovers) and residential decisions (amenity spillovers).

In the endogenous input-sourcing version of the model, production technology is vertically organised. Downstream producers sourcing from upstream suppliers along the supply chain produce a composite good in N production tiers that need to be performed sequentially. For the sake of tractability, in the baseline model we assume two tiers in the production process, though the model is more general and extends to any number of tiers straightforwardly. Firms in the upstream tier only use the local factor. Firms in the second tier combine the local factor with intermediate inputs produced in any location in the first tier. Both inputs – local factor and intermediate components – are required in the tier-two production, no output can be produced with one input only. If either labour or at least one source of intermediate inputs (or both) are not supplied, no production can take place in this location. The optimal input sourcing location at the different production tiers of the supply chain is determined by a cost minimisation of downstream firms. Final goods can be produced using different sets of intermediate inputs that can be sourced from any location. Firm-specific technique - a production function that specifies from which locations and suppliers intermediate inputs to source - can differ in terms of productivity. When choosing a production technique, a firm can adjust the importance of a supplier e.g. by including or dropping that supplier. Production techniques are chosen at the beginning of the period, firms have to produce with the selected input suppliers. These decisions, when aggregated, lead to changes in the supply network along both the intensive and extensive margins, which have implications to the supply chain's robustness. Firms can adjust the input sourcing path at the end of the period. The downstream firm’s problem in the vertically organised supply chain consists of choosing the least-cost path of production to manufacture a final composite good’s variety and deliver to consumers in their location.

model inputs

EU-EMS requires detailed data across multiple dimensions –. Key data inputs include regional economic variables like GDP, employment, and capital stock by location; trade flows between regions, capturing goods, services, and labour mobility; production and consumption data for different industries; and demographic information such as population, migration patterns, and household preferences. Additionally, infrastructure and transportation costs, regional policies, and environmental factors (e.g., land use, emissions) are crucial. Time series data is needed to capture dynamic elements like investment, technological change, and policy impacts, ensuring the model accurately simulates spatial and temporal interactions.

model outputs

Model output indicators include metrics assessing policy progress and effectiveness. For clean growth and net zero, indicators include emission reductions, energy efficiency, and renewable energy adoption. Technological sovereignty looks at innovation output and digital infrastructure. Security and democracy is measured by policy enforcement, cybersecurity, and public trust. People, skills, and preparedness gauges workforce training, education, and adaptability. Cohesion and reforms include economic equality, policy integration, and regional growth. Economic security uses productivity, trade balance, and crisis resilience. Environment indicators track resilience, circular economy progress, and sustainable transport. Overall, transparency, implementation, and simplification reflect government efficiency.

  1. Factor supply by households (capital, labour) in each region
  2. Education by skill level and region
  3. Income of households in each region
  4. Taxes payed on income by households in each region
  5. Savings of households in each region
  6. Aggregate consumption of households in each region
  7. Price index of consumption goods in each region
  8. Household consumption in each region & sector
  9. Price of exports from each NUTS2 region to each NUTS2 region
  10. Average selling price in each region & sector
  11. Average production cost in each region & sector
  12. Profits in each region & sector
  13. Fixed cost of production
  14. Marginal cost of production in each region & sector
  15. Aggregate intermediate input in each region & sector
  16. Aggregate input of primary factor in each region & sector
  17. Price of aggregate intermediate input in each region & sector
  18. Intermediate input demand in each region & sector
  19. Total factor productivity in each region & sector
  20. Aggregate capital-factor demand in each region & sector
  21. Aggregate labour-factor demand in each region & sector
  22. Price of aggregate capital-factor demand in each region & sector
  23. Price of aggregate labour-factor demand in each region & sector
  24. Price of firm output in each region & sector
  25. Demand for factors (capital, labour) in each region & sector
  26. Taxes payed on factors in each region & sector
  27. Taxes payed on intermediate inputs in each region & sector
  28. Income of investor in each region
  29. Aggregate investment in each region
  30. Price of investment good in each region
  31. Investment demand in each region & sector
  32. Supply of factors (capital, labour) by government in each region
  33. Taxes rate on household income in each region
  34. Income of government in each region
  35. Aggregate consumption of government in each region
  36. Composite price of government consumption good in each region
  37. Government consumption in each region & sector
  38. Transfers from government to households in each region
  39. Government savings
  40. Demand for composite import good in each region & sector
  41. Price of composite import good each region & sector
  42. Exports from each NUTS2 region to each NUTS2 region
  43. Price of factors (capital, labour) in each region
  44. Unemployment rate for each region
  45. Firm sales in each region & sector
  46. Number of firms in each region & sector

model spatial-temporal resolution and extent

ParameterDescription
Spatial Extent/Country Coverage
EU Member states 27EFTA countriesWestern Balkans
Spatial Resolution
National
Temporal Extent
Short-term (from 1 to 5 years)Medium-term (5 to 15 years)Long-term (more than 15 years)
2050
Temporal Resolution
Years